Skip to main content

Publication records

ESMT Case Study

A350 XWB: Airbus' answer to Boeing's Dreamliner

ESMT Case Study No. ESMT-310-0114-1
Subject(s)
Strategy and general management
Keyword(s)
timing of innovation, first mover advantage, program management, business strategy
The case study describes the strategic moves of Airbus in the twin-aisle-twin segment since the announcement by Boeing of the launch of its 787 Dreamliner. Airbus' clients initially reacted negatively to the strategic response on two occasions by criticizing the design of its competitive offering. By the end of 2006, however, there were positive signs that the new design, the A350 XWB, would be able to find its market. However, the formal industrial launch was not yet made and the A350 program management office had been asked to prepare a series of proposals to the Board of EADS regarding the next steps.
buy nowbuy nowbuy now
Journal Article

Exploiting naivete about self-control in the credit market

American Economic Review 100 (5): 2279–2303
Paul Heidhues, Botond Kőszegi (2010)
Subject(s)
Economics, politics and business environment
Keyword(s)
consumer, contracts, regulation, consumer protection
JEL Code(s)
D14, D18, D49, D86
We analyze contract choices, loan-repayment behavior, and welfare in a model of a competitive credit market when borrowers have a taste for immediate gratification. Consistent with many credit cards and subprime mortgages, for most types of nonsophisticated borrowers the baseline repayment terms are cheap, but they are also inefficiently front loaded and delays require paying large penalties. Although credit is for future consumption, nonsophisticated consumers overborrow, pay the penalties, and back load repayment, suffering large welfare losses. Prohibiting large penalties for deferring small amounts of repayment-akin to recent regulations in the US credit-card and mortgage markets-can raise welfare.
Copyright © 2012 by the American Economic Association.
Volume
100
Journal Pages
2279–2303
Journal Article

Good business makes poor customers good customers

Business Strategy Review 21 (4): 46–51
Jamie Anderson, Martin Kupp, Sandra Vandermerwe (2010)
Subject(s)
Strategy and general management
Keyword(s)
strategy, bottom of the pyramid, CSR, Nigeria, mobile phone
To date, few firms have used a customer-focused approach to serve the world's poorest people - a full two-thirds of the world's total population at the so-called 'bottom of the economic pyramid' (BOP). Much more prevalent has been a mass-produced approach that assumes that the poor in developing economies can only afford basic, cheap products emphasising functionality. In this classic product approach, often little more is done than push existing or barely adapted products onto shantytown dwellers and rural villagers. Consequently, real value that opens up new market spaces for companies and produces longer-term value for the customer has been lost. Our research reveals that contemporary enterprises that have taken the leap to the customer-focused way of doing business in the developing world grow markets and their stake in them, outperforming traditional enterprise and industry product approaches. The crucial steps in this approach are becoming better known but deserve much more attention.
© 2010 London Business School
Volume
21
Journal Pages
46–51
Journal Article

Screening and merger activity

The Journal of Industrial Economics 58 (4): 794–817
Albert Banal-Estanol, Paul Heidhues, Rainer Nitsche, Jo Seldeslachts (2010)
Subject(s)
Economics, politics and business environment
Keyword(s)
takeovers, merger waves, defense tactics, screening
JEL Code(s)
D21, D80, L11
In our paper, the target of a proposed merger, by setting a reserve price, is able to screen prospective acquirers according to their (expected) ability to generate merger-specific synergies. Both empirical evidence and many merger models suggest that the difference between high and low-synergy mergers becomes smaller during booms. Thus, a target's opportunity cost for sorting out relatively less fitting acquirers increases and, hence, targets screen less tightly during booms, which leads to a hike in merger activity. Our screening mechanism not only predicts that merger activity is intense during booms and subdued during recessions but is also consistent with other stylized facts about takeovers and generates novel testable predictions.
© The Author 2011. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Review of Economic Studies Limited.
Volume
58
Journal Pages
794–817
ESMT Case Study

Anna Frisch at Aesch AG: Initiating lateral change

ESMT Case Study No. ESMT-410-0112-1
2020 Case Writing Award, Best-selling Case , 2018 Case Writing Award, Best-selling Case , 2017 Case Writing Award, Best-selling Case , 2016 Case Writing Award, Best-selling Case , 2014 Case Writing Award, Best-selling Case , 2014 Case Writing Award: Human resource management/Organizational behavior
Urs Müller, Ulf Schäfer (2010)
Subject(s)
Human resources management/organizational behavior
Keyword(s)
initiating change, implementing change, change management, communication of change, lateral change / leading change from the middle, influencing / persuading, stakeholder management, power and politics in organizations, change in a global matrix organization
Anna Frisch has tried to initiate change at Aesch AG, a large global provider of medical devices for the healthcare industry. As marketing director, she has identified major shifts in German healthcare that demand that Aesch changes its ways of approaching customers. Instead of targeting the specific needs of doctors in hospitals, Aesch should rather address the new decision makers: the CEOs, CFOs, or CIOs of hospitals, who have a different buying logic. In Aesch's matrix organization (global product responsibility, supported by regional sales) Anna wants to convince the heads of marketing for the different product businesses to change. She seems to be able to quickly convince her colleagues of what she calls "C-level marketing." However, as soon as work is supposed to start, she realizes that commitments were less strong than she assumed. A few weeks later, Anna is clearly told that there will be no support for her.
The short case study is set when Anna realizes the failure of her change initiative. The case discussion allows analyzing and discussing various mistakes in the areas of:
- defining an attractive vision and strategy,
- reading and playing the organizational culture, power and politics,
- communicating a change initiative successfully,
- managing the stakeholders.
The case is supported by a 6-minute video showing Anna reflecting on the events, her analysis of failure, and her personal preferences as of December 2008.
buy nowbuy nowbuy now
ESMT Working Paper

Regular prices and sales

ESMT Working Paper No. 10-008
Paul Heidhues, Botond Kőszegi (2010)
Subject(s)
Economics, politics and business environment
Keyword(s)
Reference-dependent utility, gain-loss utility, loss aversion, sticky prices, sales, supermarket pricing
JEL Code(s)
D11, D43, D81, L13
We study the properties of a profit-maximizing monopolist's optimal price distribution when selling to a loss-averse consumer, where (following K?szegi and Rabin (2006)) we assume that the consumer's reference point is her recent rational expectations about the purchase. If it is close to costless for the consumer to observe the realized price of the product, then - in a pattern consistent with several recently documented facts regarding supermarket pricing - the monopolist chooses low and variable "sale" prices with some probability and a high and sticky "regular" price with the complementary probability. Realizing that she will buy at the sale prices and hence that she will purchase with positive probability, the consumer chooses to avoid the painful uncertainty in whether she will get the product by buying also at the regular price. If it is more costly for the consumer to observe the realized price, then - in a pattern consistent with the pricing behavior of some other retailers (e.g. movie theaters) - the monopolist chooses a sticky price and holds no sales. In this case, a sale is less tempting and hence less effective in generating an expectation to purchase with positive probability. We also show that ex-ante competition for loyal consumers leads to sticky pricing while ex-post competition leads to marginal-cost pricing, and discuss several other extensions of the model.

 


View all ESMT Working Papers in the ESMT Working Paper Series here. ESMT Working Papers are also available via SSRN, RePEc, EconStor, and the German National Library (DNB).

Pages
66
ISSN (Print)
1866–3494
ESMT Working Paper

Technology adoption, social learning, and economic policy

ESMT Working Paper No. 10-007
Paul Heidhues, Nicolas Melissas (2010)
Subject(s)
Economics, politics and business environment
Keyword(s)
information externality, strategic waiting, delay, information cascade, investment boom, optimal taxation
JEL Code(s)
D62, D83
We study a two-player dynamic investment model with information externalities and provide necessary and sufficient conditions for a unique switching equilibrium. Within this setup, we ask whether policymakers should interfere when better informed agents make individual investment decisions. We find that when the public information is sufficiently high and a social planer therefore expects an investment boom, investments should be taxed. Conversely, any positive investment tax is suboptimally high if the public information is sufficiently unfavorable. We also show that an investment tax may increase overall investment activity.

 

View all ESMT Working Papers in the ESMT Working Paper Series here. ESMT Working Papers are also available via SSRN, RePEc, EconStor, and the German National Library (DNB).

Pages
46
ISSN (Print)
1866–3494
Journal Article

Лаборатория идентичности [Identity laboratory]

Harvard Business Review Russia 63 (11): 1–3
Subject(s)
Human resources management/organizational behavior
Keyword(s)
identity, change, leadership development
Volume
63
Journal Pages
1–3
Journal Article

Consuming experience: Why affective forecasters overestimate comparative value

Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 46 (6): 986–992
Carey K. Morewedge, Daniel T. Gilbert, Kristian Ove R. Myrseth, Karim S. Kassam, Timothy D. Wilson (2010)
Subject(s)
Marketing
Keyword(s)
affective forecasting, comparison, attention, contrast effect, judgment and decision making
The hedonic value of an outcome can be influenced by the alternatives to which it is compared, which is why people expect to be happier with outcomes that maximize comparative value (e.g., the best of several mediocre alternatives) than with outcomes that maximize absolute value (e.g., the worst of several excellent alternatives). The results of five experiments suggest that affective forecasters overestimate the importance of comparative value because forecasters do not realize that comparison requires cognitive resources, and that experiences consume more cognitive resources than do forecasts. In other words, because forecasters overestimate the extent to which they will be able to think about what they didn't get while experiencing what they got.
With permission of Elsevier
Volume
46
Journal Pages
986–992
Journal Article

Error management in hierarchies: Lessons from the cockpit

ESMT Customized Solutions
Subject(s)
Strategy and general management