Skip to main content
đŸ”ïžŽ
Programs
Topics · Experience level
đŸŽšïžŽ
Programs
Programs
Topics
Topics
Experience level
Experience level
cancel

Publication database

Picture of various books and publications
Filter
Book

Der perfekte Businessplan [The perfect business plan]

3rd ed.,Munich: C.H. Beck
Bernd Fischl, Stefan Wagner (2016)
Subject(s)
Strategy and general management
Keyword(s)
Business planning, venture creation, entrepreneurship, start-ups
Zum Werk Businessplanung ist ein essentieller Bestandteil vor, bei und nach der GrĂŒndung eines Unternehmens. Selbst nach Etablierung eines Unternehmens sollte ein kontinuierlicher Planungsprozess und damit die Konkretisierung und Quantifizierung von Unternehmenszielen beibehalten werden. Im Mittelpunkt steht die Businessplanung von jungen Unternehmen. Hier ist der Planungsbedarf am grĂ¶ĂŸten aber auch zugleich am schwierigsten zu gestalten. Um eine solide Informationsgrundlage fĂŒr (potenzielle und tatsĂ€chliche) GrĂŒnder und Jungunternehmer zu haben, werden im vorliegenden Buch die relevanten Bereiche einer adĂ€quaten GeschĂ€ftsplanung dargestellt und erlĂ€utert. Vorteile auf einen Blick - Schritt fĂŒr Schritt zum perfekten Businessplan - praxisorientiert und sofort umsetzbar - Tipps fĂŒr die ĂŒberzeugende PrĂ€sentation vor Investoren und Bankern Zielgruppe FĂŒr ExistenzgrĂŒnder und Unternehmer
Volume
3rd ed.,
Pages
180
ISBN
978-3406681080
ESMT Working Paper

LeChatelier-Samuelson principle in games and pass-through of shocks

ESMT Working Paper No. 15-03 (R1)
Published in Journal of Economic Theory, 168 (3): 44–54.
Alexei Alexandrov, Özlem Bedre-Defolie (2016)
Subject(s)
Economics, politics and business environment
Keyword(s)
LeChatelier-Samuelson principle, cost passthrough, multiproduct firms
The LeChatelier-Samuelson principle states that as a reaction to a shock, an agent's short-run adjustment of an action is smaller than the long-run adjustment of that action when the other related actions can also be adjusted. We extend the principle to strategic environments and define long run as an adjustment that also includes other players adjusting their strategies. We show that the principle holds for both idiosyncratic shocks (affecting only one player's action directly) and common shocks in supermodular games, only for idiosyncratic shocks in submodular games if the players' payoffs depend only on their own strategies and the sum of the rivals' strategies (for example, homogeneous Cournot oligopoly), and only for idiosyncratic shocks in other games of strategic substitutes or heterogeneity satisfying Morishima Conditions. We argue that the principle might also explain the empirical findings of overshifting of cost and unit tax by multiproduct firms.

 

View all ESMT Working Papers in the ESMT Working Paper Series here. ESMT Working Papers are also available via SSRN, RePEc, EconStor, and the German National Library (DNB).

Pages
46
ISSN (Print)
1866–3494
Journal Article

Efficient feed-in-tariff policies for renewable energy technologies

Operations Research 64 (1): 52–66
Saed Alizamir, Francis de VĂ©ricourt, Peng Sun (2016)
Subject(s)
Management sciences, decision sciences and quantitative methods; Product and operations management
Keyword(s)
Technology diffusion, government incentive policies, renewable energy technology, feed-in tariff, learning-by-doing, dynamic programming
Feed-in-tariff (FIT) policies aim at driving down the cost of renewable energies by fostering learning and accelerating the diffusion of green technologies. Under FIT mechanisms, governments purchase green energy at tariffs that are set above market price. The success or failure of FIT policies, in turn, critically depend on how these tariffs are determined and adjusted over time. This paper provides insights into designing cost-efficient and socially-optimal FIT programs. Our modeling framework captures key market dynamics as well as investors' strategic behavior. In this framework, we establish that the current practice of maintaining constant profitability is theoretically rarely optimal. By contrast, we characterize a no-delay region in the problem's parameters, such that profitability should strictly decrease over time if the diffusion and learning rates belong to this region. In this case, investors never strategically postpone their investment to a later period. When the diffusion and learning rates fall outside the region, profitability should increase at least temporarily over some time periods and strategic delays occur. The presence of strategic delays, however, makes the practical problem of computing optimal FIT schedules very difficult. To address this issue, the regulator may focus on policies that disincentivize investors to postpone their investment. With this additional constraint, a constant profitability policy is optimal if and only if the diffusion and learning rates fall outside the no-delay region. This provides partial justifications for current FIT implementations.
© 2015 INFORMS
Volume
64
Journal Pages
52–66
Journal Article

How the ‘Big Beyond' will change business models of utilities

Oxford Energy Forum 26 (104): 8–11
Subject(s)
Technology, R&D management
Volume
26
Journal Pages
8–11
ESMT Case Study

Dr. Semmelweis at Vienna General Hospital

ESMT Case Study No. ESMT-416-0168-1
Ulf SchÀfer (2016)
Subject(s)
Human resources management/organizational behavior
Keyword(s)
Change, change management, adaptive change, adaptive leadership, resistance to change, decision making, paradigmatic change, (natural) experiment, scientific method, theory of science, history of science, error management, R&D management
The case provides an example of an individual who meets harsh criticism, personal attacks, and broad resistance despite clear evidence that what he is proposing is right and could save the lives of thousands of human beings. The case recounts the story of Dr. Ignaz Philip Semmelweis, a pioneer in medical antiseptic procedures who is today known as “the savior of mothers.” In 1847, Semmelweis discovered that the practice of hand disinfection in obstetrical clinics can effectively eliminate the outbreak of puerperal fever (“childbed fever”), a condition that killed up to 30 percent of mothers and babies in maternity clinics at the time of the case. The relatively short case – which is designed to be handed out during class – is divided into three parts. Part A describes the situation at Vienna General Hospital in 1846, when Semmelweis is assigned to head one of the two maternity clinics. Much of this part is dedicated to describing the natural experiment that Semmelweis encountered when learning that the two clinics had vastly different mortality rates. Part B lists the many hypotheses that Semmelweis had formulated and refuted, reports on his discovery that the contamination of women by doctors performing anatomical dissections of corpses is causing puerperal fever, and reveals his findings that it can be easily and effectively treated through hand disinfection. Part C provides an account of the resistance he faced from the medical establishment, despite the overwhelming evidence that Semmelweis had collected in support of his findings.
The case has the potential to be an eye-opening experience, as it describes a situation in which the protagonist of change is unable to convince the relevant community, despite having clear evidence: Semmelweis can prove that he is right, but instead of receiving recognition and gratitude and having his recommendations adopted, he meets resistance, personal attack, and ridicule. This is an important lesson for students, who often believe that change can effectively be brought to groups, organizations, and societies when there is clear evidence that proves the integrity of a new proposition.
buy nowbuy nowbuy now
Journal Article

Technology isn't enough to empower employees, even in a digital world

Harvard Business Review
Donald A. Marchand, Joe Peppard (2016)
Subject(s)
Information technology and systems; Technology, R&D management
Over the last 10 years, a basic shift has occurred from an IT-deployment view of the world of big systems and even bigger projects toward a people-centric and user-oriented view of hardware, information, and human collaboration and networking. Consumers have adapted rather quickly to this shift: If it is not useful, delete the app, the data, and the humans we choose not to network with. While consumers are free to pick and choose the technology they will buy, the information they will access, and the degree to which they will network and with whom, managers and employees within companies are more constrained by the processes, structures, functions, systems, and technology the company invests in and deploys over time. So we have a fundamental dilemma: How must leaders align and transform their legacy business to take full advantage how people, information, and IT capabilities can interact in a rapidly changing, digital world?
ISSN (Print)
0017-8012
Journal Article

Effects of upstream and downstream mergers on supply chain profitability

European Journal of Operational Research 249 (1): 131–143
Jing Zhu, Tamer Boyaci, Saibal Ray (2016)
Subject(s)
Product and operations management
Keyword(s)
Mergers, supply chain, differentiated products, market power, operational synergy
This paper studies the implications of upstream and/or downstream horizontal mergers on suppliers, retailers and consumers, in a bilateral oligopolistic system. We especially focus on market power and operational synergy benefits that such mergers engender. Starting with a benchmark pre-merger scenario in which firms compete on prices at each level, we find that the above two consequences individually almost have opposite effects on the merging and non-merging firms’ optimal decisions/profits after a merger. Furthermore, even though the effects of upstream and downstream mergers are different, the vertical supply chain partners will always try to reduce their losses if the market power effect dominates, but will take actions that improve their profits if the synergy effect is stronger. The above results are robust enough to hold even when taking into account intra-brand competition among retailers.
With permission of Elsevier
Volume
249
Journal Pages
131–143
Editorial

From the Editors: Reputation and status: Expanding the role of social evaluations in management research

Academy of Management Journal 59 (1): 1–13
Gerard George, Linus Dahlander, Scott D. Graffin, Samantha Sim (2016)
Subject(s)
Technology, R&D management
Volume
59
Journal Pages
1–13
Journal Article

Corporate social responsibility: A consumer psychology perspective

Current Opinion in Psychology 10: 70–75
Sankar Sen, Shuili Du, CB Bhattacharya (2016)
Subject(s)
Ethics and social responsibility; Marketing
This paper reviews the substantial body of work on corporate social responsibility (CSR), including the synonymous domains of cause-related marketing and ethical consumption, to synthesizes the diverse findings on consumer responses to CSR. CSR is capable of engendering a range of company-favoring perceptions and behaviors, driven by both consumers’ CSR-related motivations (e.g., consumer-company identification, affective motives) and their CSR-guided product perceptions. As well, the paper documents the plethora of CSR initiative-, company-, and consumer-specific factors that modulate consumers’ reactions to CSR initiatives, and ends with a discussion of some key future research directions.
With permission of Elsevier
Volume
10
Journal Pages
70–75
Journal Article

Exploitative innovation

American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 8 (1): 1–23
Paul Heidhues, Botond Köszegi, Takeshi Murooka (2016)
Subject(s)
Economics, politics and business environment
Keyword(s)
Consumer naivete, innovation, exploitative contracting, consumer protection, retail finance
JEL Code(s)
D21, G21, L11, L25, O31
We analyze innovation incentives when firms can invest either in increasing the product's value (value-increasing innovation) or in increasing the hidden prices they collect from naive consumers (exploitative innovation). We show that if firms cannot return all profits from hidden prices by lowering transparent prices, innovation incentives are often stronger for exploitative than for value-increasing innovations, and are strong even for non-appropriable innovations. These results help explain why firms in the financial industry (e.g. credit-card issuers) have been willing to make innovations others could easily copy, and why these innovations often seem to have included exploitative features.
Copyright © 2015 by the American Economic Association.
Volume
8
Journal Pages
1–23